Archive for April, 2007

Australian property good investment? Part 3?prospects of capital appreciation

Sunday, April 29th, 2007
For today?s article, we will continue from our previous 2 articles: Australian property good investment??Part 1: how money printing distort the property market and Australian property good investment? Part 2?Rental & affordability crisis.

These days, we often get to hear about the looming social crisis caused by housing un-affordability and rental crisis. From the news media, we get to see articles like Is the great Australian dream out of reach? and Rents continue to rise, but no relief is in sight. These issues are most likely going to be hot topics in this election year, with politicians and special interest groups arguing, blaming each other and giving their own versions of the causes and solutions to this problem. Make no mistake about this: the root of all these issues are caused by monetary inflation (see How to secretly rob the people with monetary inflation?), which will eventually spill over to price inflation in due time.

No doubt, there are some people who are thinking of ?investing? into property. Is that a good investment decision? Of course, for truly sophisticated property investors with the knowledge, skill and experience, it is possible to profit regardless of the timing and state of the property market. But for the purpose of today?s article, we will talk about property ?investments? from the context of the mum and dads investors.

First, how do property ?investors? profit from their property ?investments?? There are two perceived sources of profit?capital appreciation (i.e. buy low, sell high or buy high, sell higher) and net rental income. Today, we will examine the former.

What drives capital appreciation of property? Traditionally, it is the rising income levels that drive property prices upwards over the years. Naturally, as people?s general income level increases, the prices paid for property will increase as well. Recently, we have another phenomena that drive property prices upwards?the sudden availability of easy credit and low interest rates, which are manifestations of monetary inflation (?printing? of money). The result is a short-term property price bubble, which is currently deflating slowly. Japan, on the other hand, had their property price bubble burst, which led to a long painful recession and continuous deflation of property prices for around 17 years.

In Australia?s case, what are the prospects of capital appreciation? As we said before in Australian property good investment? Part 2?Rental & affordability crisis:

Eventually, the ever increasing amount of debt required to finance a price bubble will result in a debt burden so heavy that no more additional borrowings can be made. As such, the price inflation will sooner or later be halted.

The current housing affordability and rental crisis is a sign that at the current level of income, the strain of debt burden is too heavy to support higher property prices. Until income levels catch up with current property price levels, we will not see income as a driver for property prices. How likely is income going to fulfil this role? Remember, we are currently at the turning point of the business cycle (see Where are we in the business cycle?). Any accelerating economic ?growth? will lead to price inflation (see Pitfalls for businesses in ?accelerating? economy). Given that the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA)?s mandate is to control price inflation, it will step in to raise interest rates the moment it sees threats of price inflation in the horizon. A rise in income levels without the accompanying real economic growth is highly inflationary in nature.

If current income levels cannot drive property prices upward, then this leaves the availability of credit as the next candidate. In other worse, why not loosen credit standards so that more people can borrow more money? Indeed, this is what happened in the US and the results are ugly (see How did the US sub-prime lenders get into trouble?). Well, if the Australian economy becomes a runaway credit machine running, we can be sure the RBA will be very keen to force feed more bitter medicines into the economy. But what happens if credit standards get tightened instead? When that happens, less people can borrow less money, which means it is harder for property prices to rise further. Anecdotally, our personal experience tells us that credit standards seem to be tightening across all board.

The next thing to consider is price inflation. Suppose headline price inflation is swelling in the absence of wage increases. This means that the debt repayment burden is going to rise, which means that the affordability of property is going to fall. Furthermore, with rising expected price inflation, people are going to perceive that their housing stress is going to increase. At the same time, the RBA may be pressured to raise interest rates (see Price inflation expectation will pressure RBA to raise interest rates). Either way, price inflation is a threat against property prices rising.

Next, there is always the threat of debt-driven asset price deflation caused by an external economic shock. See Can Australia?s deflating property bubble deflate even further?.

Thus, for those who are hoping profit from their property ?investment? via capital appreciation, be prepared to be disappointed.


How dangerous are credit derivatives?

Friday, April 27th, 2007

A few months ago, in Prepare for asset repricing, warns Trichet, we reported that:

With such massive quantity of derivatives sloshing around the global financial market, there is very little wonder that no one, not even governments or central banks can fully understand what is going on.

Indeed, the growth of derivatives looks to be in an exponentially upward trend: Credit Derivatives Doubled for Third Straight Year (Update2). How dangerous is this development of modern finance?

According to the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA)?s March 2007 Financial Stability Review, it has the following comments:

Rapid growth in the use of credit derivatives is also posing financial regulators with a number of issues relating to transparency. In some cases, the balance sheet data received from financial institutions are becoming less meaningful, as 15 credit exposures are taken on or divested through derivatives. The growth of credit derivatives markets has also meant that it is less clear where the credit risk actually resides, and how those holding this risk will react in a less benign environment…. This intersection of private equity, hedge funds and credit derivatives is rapidly transforming credit markets. This transformation is mostly for the better, improving the allocation of global capital, and leading to risk being more broadly held than in the past. Despite this, there remains considerable uncertainty as to how the system would react to a very large shock. It is possible that the very developments that have contributed to the increased robustness of the financial system to most events, through the wider dispersion of risk, could actually amplify the disruption following a serious shock. In particular, there is uncertainty about just how credit risk transfer markets, on which so many institutions now rely, might perform. Dealing with this potential paradox – a decline in the likelihood of a significant disruption but an increase in the potential costs of such a disruption – is likely to remain a key issue over the years ahead for central banks and financial regulators charged with maintaining financial stability.

Today, it has come to the point that the risk to the global financial system through the widespread use of derivatives is beyond the understanding and control of central banks and regulators. Furthermore, though derivatives make the chances of things going wrong less likely, the outcome is far worse when they really go wrong.

What does this means for us? It means that the conventional risk model uses by much of the financial industry cannot spot such dangers. That is why Warren Buffet said that ?Certain perils that lurk in investment strategies cannot be spotted by use of the models commonly employed today by financial institutions.? (see Myth of diversification as safety?Part 2: nature of risk).

Therefore, we see that hedging is still wise.

Politicians cannot be trusted to tell truth about rental crisis

Wednesday, April 25th, 2007

We saw this interesting article: Tenants take landlords to tribunal over rents surge. In that article, it reported that:

The Prime Minister, John Howard, yesterday backed away from an offer of rent relief, blaming the crisis on the states’ failure to release land. The federal Treasurer, Peter Costello, blamed a pause in home building.

As we can see from this example, it is another load of nonsense from politicians? mouths. Either they are ignorant or they are lying.

Suppose the state government release vast tracts of land for home building. Will it really solve the problem? As we said before in Australian property good investment??Part 1: how money printing distort the property market,

The additional investments by builders into building houses can only be completed if you have complementary capital (e.g. land, infrastructure, equipment, labour, etc) already invested. Because monetary inflation distorts the price signals to the builders, they engage in an investment boom that will be doomed to failure because these complementary capitals did not suffice.

If the state government really do that, and assuming that builders really build houses on these newly released land, we will have a lot of houses built in the middle of nowhere (i.e. houses built with no complementary infrastructure). In that case, who would want to buy or rent such houses?

Next, why is there a pause in home building? As we said before in Australian property good investment? Part 2?Rental & affordability crisis,

Builders soon faced problems of land scarcity, lagging infrastructure, soaring labour cost and so on. This is what the Austrian School calls mal-investment of capital.

The previous excess and imbalance led to the current dearth and bust.

Australian property good investment? Part 2?Rental & affordability crisis

Tuesday, April 24th, 2007
Today, continuing from our previous article, Australian property good investment??Part 1: how money printing distort the property market, we will look at how the current rental crisis developed.

Let us assume that the housing property market was initially at a state of equilibrium i.e. demand met supply at a particular price. As it always happen, any injection of excess liquidity (i.e. ?printing? of money, which resulted in an increase in money and credit) will eventually cause a distortion to the economy?inflation of prices. The question is, which asset class (e.g. stocks, bonds) or ?things? (e.g. consumer prices, wages) will bear the brunt of price inflation? As it happened, thanks to the Howard government?s loophole on negative gearing and concessions on capital gains tax, that excess liquidity flowed on to houses, which resulted in a price bubble.

With such artificially induced excess demand for housing, the property market fell into disequilibrium. With such rampant availability of easy credit, the demand increased at a given price. In economic jargon, it means that the demand ?curve? had shifted to the right. The outcome was a ?shortage? of houses, which prompted property developers to increase production to meet the ?demand? shortfall. As we can easily see from hindsight, the economy was not structured to cope with such artificially induced demand. Builders soon faced problems of land scarcity, lagging infrastructure, soaring labour cost and so on. This is what the Austrian School calls mal-investment of capital (our previous article, Australian property good investment??Part 1: how money printing distort the property market will lead you to further explanations on the concept of mal-investment).

As common sense tells us, asset prices cannot rise forever and ever. Eventually, the ever increasing amount of debt required to finance a price bubble will result in a debt burden so heavy that no more additional borrowings can be made. As such, the price inflation will sooner or later be halted. Next, came RBA?s interest rates rise, which forced many ?investors? into forced liquidation of their property ?investments? because the debt servicing burden of their ?investments? no longer make economic sense. Furthermore, if easy credit boosted demand artificially, what would happen if such easy credit got tightened? Well, easy come, easy goes.

To give you an appreciation how the reality meets this theory of ours, we will relate to you a real story. One of our friends was in the property development businesses during the boom years. Recently, he pulled out of this business as he found it harder and harder to make money as margins were squeezed to the point that his business was no longer profitable. As our above analysis had shown, with falling demand (which was artificially induced in the first place) and rising cost, margins will have to fall.

So, how does all these relate to the housing affordability and rental crisis? The former is easy to understand?easy money caused property prices to be so high that many people were priced out of the market. The latter is what we will concentrate on today. First, we will state the obvious?the current rental crisis tells us that the demand for rental properties is getting tight relative to its supply. From this, we will then look at the supply side followed by the demand side of the problem.

Now, let us look at the supply side of this issue. As we all know, the building industry is in a recession. As a result, from what we can learn from the mainstream media, not enough are being built to supply enough rental properties to a market with growing demand. As expected, the ?solution? that is often mentioned by them is to build more housing. The only way for this to happen is to entice ?investors? back in to the market, in the hope of revitalising the building industry through higher property prices, which will result in a restoration of ?healthy? profit margins. Obviously, guess who will benefit from this ?solution??

Now, let us look at the demand side of this issue. We can see the demand for rental properties in the market as a pool of rent seekers. Every year, there will be some people entering the pool and some leaving the pool. Those entering the pool may include young adults leaving home, people leaving shared accommodation, couples divorcing, newly arrived migrants and so on. Those leaving the pool may include people passing away, couples getting married and people leaving the rental market by buying their own property. Lately, the pool is getting bigger and bigger. Why? We suspect one of the major contributing factors is the housing affordability problem, especially for young people. Because housing is largely unaffordable to a large segment of society, it serves as an impediment for them to leave the rental market through the acquirement of their own property. If they cannot leave the rental pool, it can only lead the pool getting larger as more and more people enters the pool.

In view of all these, we doubt higher property prices and more ‘investments’ are the solutions to the current affordability and rental crisis. It will only exacerbate the problem for Australians in the long run. In the next article, we will evaluate on the merits of property investments. Keep in tune!


Austrian School view of inflation in mainstream media

Tuesday, April 24th, 2007

Today, we are pleased to see the Austrian School of economic thought being reported in the mainstream media: RBA policy ‘causing inflation’. For this, we applaud.

Australian property good investment??Part 1: how money printing distort the property market

Friday, April 20th, 2007
At this point in time, rental vacancies rate in Australia are at record lows (see Rental vacancies lowest on record). One finance commentator commented that it is so low that it should be considered a ?rental crisis.? He believes that this can only mean one thing?rents and property price are going to increase. As such, some investors are returning to the property market.

For us, we have some reservations on the merits of property as investment. Granted, you may not lose money if you invest in property today, but we doubt it is the best place for wealth. Furthermore, property investments are not as risk free as some may assume, as we said before in Those who have knowledge don?t predict. Those who predict, don?t have knowledge:

To give you an example, we recently heard this assumption, which was manifested in the form of an advice: ?Don?t worry about investing in property. They will never go down in value in the long run.? Try telling that to the Japanese in the early 1990s when their property bubble crashed?those who bought and held out at the top had to wait for decades to recoup their loss.

We will start on a series on the topic of: Are Australian property good investment? Today, we will examine the origins of this rental crisis. Only with a proper understand of it can we then evaluate the merits of property as investments in this current investment climate.

First, what caused the existence of a property bubble (especially in Sydney) in the first place? For the answer to this question, we suggest that you read our earlier article, The Bubble Economy. In short, the property bubble is the result of monetary inflation (aka ?printing? of money) and not due to a sudden and disproportionate increase in ?demand? for housing. To fully understand what monetary inflation is, we recommend that you read this article, Cause of inflation: Shanghai bubble case study. The property bubble in Shanghai is even far worse than Sydney?it defies all rudiments of proportion, common sense and prudence.

Next, how did monetary inflation distorts the property market? As we said before in Wasteful investment not the cause of housing un-affordability,

When money was too cheap [that is a manifestation of monetary inflation], it artificially induced a boom in demand for housing. Builders, upon seeing the rise in price as a result of the artificial boom, rushed to construct more homes than what was really required by the underlying demand. As a result, wasteful investments were made by the housing industry.

How does this work? First, let us examine the concept of inflation from our previous article, Cause of inflation: Shanghai bubble case study:

Consider the case of a fixed money supply. Whenever people increase their demand for some goods and services, money will be allocated toward other goods. Thus, the prices of some goods will increase?i.e., more money will be spent on them?while the prices of other goods will fall?i.e., less money will be spent on them.

Let?s say you are a builder and you see that house prices have been increasing rapidly. What would be your conclusion? You will surely conclude that there is an increase in demand for houses. If the money supply is fixed, then it means that this increase in demand for houses imply a decrease in demand for some other things in the economy. Therefore, the price of a good is a signal to producers that there?s a shortage or glut of that good. In a free market economy, this will divert resources from the production of things in glut to the things in shortage. Now, what happens if the money supply is not fixed i.e. money is printed and fed into the economy? As we discussed before in How to secretly rob the people with monetary inflation?, this implies that there is more money chasing the same amount of goods. The extra newly printed money has to go somewhere and in this case, goes to house price. A question to ask: Are there any changes in the economy that necessitate such an exaggerated increase in demand for houses beyond its fundamentals?

As you can see by now, easy money (i.e. monetary inflation aka ?printing? of money) distort the price signals in the economy and misallocate resources in the economy that would not have happened in a truly free market economy.

However, some may say that the current building bust is due to factors like land scarcity, lagging infrastructure and so on. For their argument, we have a counter-argument. Their argument further validate the Austrian School?s concept of mal-investments (see our article, The first step in an economic slowdown?mal-investment in capital). Capital (which is an Austrian concept that has different meaning) has structure. Ludwig von Mises, said it nicely:

It is customary to describe the boom as overinvestment. However, additional investment is only possible to the extent that there is an additional supply of capital goods available. As, apart from forced saving, the boom itself does not result in a restriction but rather in an increase in consumption, it does not procure more capital goods for new investment. The essence of the credit-expansion boom is not overinvestment, but investment in wrong lines, i.e., malinvestment. The entrepreneurs employ the available supply of r + p1 + p2 as if they were in a position to employ a supply of r + p1 + p2 + p3 + p4. They embark upon an expansion of investment on a scale for which the capital goods available do not suffice. Their projects are unrealizable on account of the insufficient supply of capital goods. They must fail sooner or later. The unavoidable end of the credit expansion makes the faults committed visible.

The additional investments by builders into building houses can only be completed if you have complementary capital (e.g. land, infrastructure, equipment, labour, etc) already invested. Because monetary inflation distorts the price signals to the builders, they engage in an investment boom that will be doomed to failure because these complementary capitals did not suffice. For example, as you can see, land gets more and more expensive. Infrastructures are non-existent. There are labour shortages. If the price signals to builders were not distorted in the first place, then those booms of building activity would not have gone so fast as to outstrip the shortage of complementary capital.

In the next article of this series, we will examine how this distortion leads to this current rental crisis. Keep in tune!


Price inflation expectation will pressure RBA to raise interest rates

Thursday, April 19th, 2007

In a recent inflation survey conducted by the Melbourne Institute, more than 77% of respondent believe that prices will increase in the next 12 months (see Consumer prices expected to rise).

One of the things that central bankers fear is expected inflation?the rise in price that people are expecting in the future. The problem with expected inflation is that it can become a self-fulfilling prophecy. When it becomes so, a self-reinforcing vicious cycle takes place. That is why central bankers are always keen to maintain credibility as an inflation ?fighter.? However, as we said before, the idea that central bankers ?fight? inflation is absurd?they are the very source of inflation (see Cause of inflation: Shanghai bubble case study)!

For those who want interest rates to remain low, this inflation survey news is bad news. See our warning: More pain for Australia.

Expect the unexpected with risk models that can’t anticipate the future

Wednesday, April 18th, 2007

In Myth of diversification as safety?Part 2: nature of risk, we quoted Warren Buffet,

Certain perils that lurk in investment strategies cannot be spotted by use of the models commonly employed today by financial institutions.

In How the folks in the finance industry got the idea of ?risk? wrong!, we questioned the assumption of the concept of ?risk? used in most financial models in the finance industry.

Today, we appluad this article, Expect the unexpected with risk models that can’t anticipate the future in the mainstream media.

Those who have knowledge don?t predict. Those who predict, don?t have knowledge

Tuesday, April 17th, 2007

In this time of rampant financial speculation and gambling, we should again remind ourselves of the wise words of Lao Tzu, an ancient Chinese philosopher, ?Those who have knowledge don?t predict. Those who predict don?t have knowledge.?

Exactly what do we mean by ?predict?? Surely, if we are in the business of investing, we have to do some form of ?prediction.? Otherwise, we may as well hide our money under our pillow and do nothing. But if you think about it, doing nothing about your money is also a form of ?prediction.? By doing that, you are ?predicting? (more accurately, assuming) that your money is worth as much today as in the future (i.e. there is no risk of price inflation).

When we say that we should not predict the financial markets, we mean that we should not have assumptions of what is going to happen in the future and base our investment decision according to these assumptions. When we do that, we will not have any contingency plans to deal with what may happen if our assumptions turn out to be wrong. If we listen to our thoughts carefully, we will surely uncover many assumptions that we have made. Often, assumptions are used to substitute gaps in knowledge.

If our lack of financial literacy results in us making too many assumptions, the results will eventually show up in loss of wealth. For some people, such loss can threaten their financial security. To give you an example, we recently heard this assumption, which was manifested in the form of an advice: ?Don?t worry about investing in property. They will never go down in value in the long run.? Try telling that to the Japanese in the early 1990s when their property bubble crashed?those who bought and held out at the top had to wait for decades to recoup their loss. Today, we marvel at those ?investors? who recently flocked back into the property market in Australia. Are they still making the same assumption in the face of contrary evidence? Make no mistake about this: we believe Australia?s property market still has room for further deflation, either in nominal terms or in real terms (see Can Australia?s deflating property bubble deflate even further?). We will discuss about this soon.

So, watch the assumptions hidden inside the inner recess of your mind!

Election vote buying can fuel further inflation

Monday, April 16th, 2007

Today, this article, Budget surplus at risk, caught our attention.

This year is an election year and we would not be surprised if the government will entice the electorate with tax cuts or some other form of bribes. Let us see how inflationary it will be. If so, it will give the Reserve Bank a stronger case to raise interest rates.